Thursday, August 27, 2015

Sleepless in Kiev




Conflict in Ukraine: The unwinding of the post-Cold War order
By Rajan Menon and Eugene Rumer
The MIT Press.  2015.

The Ukrainian crisis stemmed from what must have struck the Kremlin as quotidian arm-twisting.  In November 2013, President Victor Yanukovych was on the verge of signing a pact with the European Union that would have made Ukraine an ally, though not a member, of the EU.   

Putin countered with a bouquet of carrots and sticks.  Russia would lend $15 billion, which was the amount that the International Monetary Fund had said it would lend before it backed away, in 2011, when Yanukovych had refused its strict conditions.  The Kremlin would also knock off almost a third of the price of the natural gas that it sold to Kiev -- a $3 billion discount.  And only God knows what goodies were in store for Yanukovych & Friends.  In return, Mr. President need only tell the EU to take a hike and sign up instead with Putin’s customs union.  Kazakhstan and Belarus were already members.  And if Yanukovych refused?  Well… about that natural gas….

Yanukovych had not anticipated that accepting an $18 billion gift, maybe with a little lagniappe, would draw a hundred thousand demonstrators into the streets of Kiev.  In February 2014, when the confrontations had turned bloody, he hightailed it to Russia, which received him with noses held high.  Yulia Timoshenko was released from prison, as the EU had long demanded.  The old outsiders became the new insiders:  The new president, Petro Poroshenko, had been an official under Yanukovych.

The revolution set the scene for the Kremlin’s favorite strategy – divide and conquer.  “Local separatism… had been used and worked well in Transnistria, Abkhazia, and South Ossetia by creating permanent frozen conflicts that became Russian outposts for protecting and projecting Russian power…,” write Menon, a professor at the City College of New York, and Rumer, a director at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.  Crimea would make an ideal outpost, since it was already home to a Russian navy and to thousands of retirees from Soviet military life.  The Russians went to work.  By March, Crimea had parted ways with Ukraine.

Frozen treats

To the Kremlin, Crimea was valuable because it could check Ukrainian aspirations to join the North Atlantic Treaty Organization.  As NATO expanded in the early 2000s, doubling its number of member states, Russia fretted.  There was no longer a Warsaw Pact to counter NATO’s encroachments.  To understand Russia’s touchiness, “imagine what the American reaction would have been had the Soviet Union won the Cold War, incorporated Canada and Mexico and the other Central American states into the Warsaw Pact, and declared that Washington had no cause for worry….”

Still, Russia may fret too much.  “Throughout the crisis,” the authors note, “NATO leaders have shown no interest in offering Ukraine membership….[They] have made clear that a military conflict with Russia over Ukraine is out of the question.”  The first secretary-general of NATO, Lord Ismay, once joked that the organization’s aim was “to keep the Russians out, the Americans in, and the Germans down.” Russia was to be out, but not down and out.

NATO’s reluctance miffs the Baltic states – Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania – which draw virtually all of their natural gas from Russia and fear Kremlin coercion in the depths of winter. But the Kremlin might well prefer a frozen conflict in east Ukraine to outright annexation.  A frozen conflict would “spare [Russia] the costs and the uncertainties of a military occupation” and yet enable it to intervene in Ukraine. 

Prudence is the better half of power politics.  In 2010, the US and the EU accounted for nearly half of the global economy (measured as gross domestic product); the EU alone accounted for nearly half of Russia’s trade in 2013, particularly Germany.  You don’t want to mess around for too long with customers like these.  The alternative for the Kremlin – allying with China, with which it shares a 2,670-mile border – could occasion conflicts that, for Russia, are anything but frozen. -- Leon Taylor tayloralmaty@gmail.com    






Friday, August 21, 2015

Going for double broke



Has the National Bank of Kazakhstan blundered?

Nobody has ever accused the National Bank of being dull.  Yesterday, after managing the exchange rate since before the financial crisis of 2008, the central bank abruptly consigned the tenge to the currency market.  The tenge immediately weakened by more than a third.  If it follows its historical pattern, this may be just the beginning.

The float was not inevitable.  The government had plenty of money with which to defend the tenge.  Since December, the National Bank’s net international reserves have been holding steady at $28 billion, enough to cover eight months of imports.  The National Fund, which consists mainly of taxes on oil export revenues, did fall by more than 1% in July but still amounted to $68 billion.  However, people have been expecting devaluation ever since the last one, in February 2014; and the recent weakening of the renminbi reinforced those expectations.  The National Bank didn’t have enough credibility to change them. 

As a result, the tenge has been declining steadily since November, when it stood at 181 to the US dollar.  The rate of depreciation picked up in mid-July, when the exchange rate was 187.  Thanks to the Chinese devaluation, it rose to 190 just before the float.         

How to panic the banks

The immediate worry is that the float may endanger commercial banks.  They never recovered from the collapse of 2008; as late as 2013, loans that had been overdue for more than 90 days still comprised 30% of total bank loans.  (Recently the head of the central bank, Kairat Kelimbetov, said the bad-loan ratio had fallen to 10%, according to the business weekly Panorama.)   So, bank income from interest payments was anemic to begin with.  Now, thanks to the float, the foreign value of their tenge-denominated assets may drop by 35%.  When selling those assets for dollars, the banks will have to absorb a crushing loss.  The banks’ creditors may pull their dollars out, if the National Bank does not impose currency controls.

Also, the float makes imports more costly for retirees living on tenge accounts.  Their standard of living will fall.  

The float may raise interest rates sharply in Kazakhstan.  People expect the tenge to continue to depreciate and thus will hold tenge-denominated assets only if a higher interest rate today will compensate them for the loss of purchasing power over foreign products in the future.  High interest rates may discourage physical investment in Kazakhstan, slowing the economy at a time when falling oil prices are already eroding export revenues.  The benchmark interest rate – the refinancing rate, which the National Bank charges for loans to commercial banks – has been 5.5% since 2013; that may change.

Most troubling of all, the float is a Pandora’s box.  Historically, when the tenge went haywire, it continued to oscillate for several months.  The graph below shows fluctuations in the tenge’s monthly real exchange rate (that is, the exchange rate adjusted for domestic and foreign prices) for January 1995 through March 2014.  The thing to note is that the spikes occur in clusters of several months.  An exchange rate of 257 to the dollar is not likely to be the end of the story.   


The long-run picture is a bit brighter.  After a year or so, the depreciation should boost exports, since the dollar or euro will be able to buy more tenge than before.  Similarly, it should discourage imports, since the tenge can buy less than before of foreign currencies.  Kazakhstan’s trade balance would improve.  In the first quarter of this year, net exports amounted to nearly $4.2 billion.

Policymakers may sigh with relief, since the float frees the National Bank to target income or inflation. For example, it might be able to increase output for a while by creating money, since this encourages spending.  The Bank wasn’t at liberty to do this when it had committed itself to holding the tenge to 190 per dollar or stronger, because creating tenge raises the exchange rate (that is, weakens the tenge).

In short, the float may be more beneficial in the long run than in the short.  Nevertheless, the National Bank is no longer credible, since it had vowed to avoid a drastic devaluation ever since the February 2014 markdown.   

Since people no longer believe what the Bank says, it may have a tough time containing long-run inflation, because this depends on expectations.  If workers think that prices will be 10% higher next year, they will pressure their employers for a 10% pay hike.  The boss will pass on this cost to the consumer by raising prices.  This feeds inflation; that is, the expectation of higher prices is a self-fulfilling prophecy.  Had workers believed that the central bank would avoid inflation, they would not have asked for cost-of-living adjustments, and we would not have gotten inflation.  But the National Bank no longer has that kind of reputation.

The instability stemming from the float may help convince the Eurasian Economic Union, the Russian-led group that includes Kazakhstan, to move towards a common currency (read: the ruble).  Kazakhstan could lose the power to steer its own economy.

No, the National Bank has never been dull.  Unfortunately. – Leon Taylor, tayloralmaty@gmail.com

Notes
    
1.  All statistics cited here are from the Web site of the National Bank, www.nationalbank.kz.  The data for the real exchange rate shown in the graph are also from the National Bank.  I thank Aizhan Smailova and Adilet Danyshpan for help in gathering data.

2.  To generate a measure of volatility, I took logs of the real exchange rate and estimated the first difference (over time) in these logs.  This provided a rate of return, since the differential of a log provides a relative change, dY/Y.  Finally, I subtracted from this measure the mean rate of return over time, in order to identify unusually large increases or decreases in the return.  The graph shows that large changes in the return tend to cluster -- even when the National Bank is trying to steady the exchange rate by intervening in the forex market. 
 
The real exchange rate is prone to what economists call “autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity,” or ARCH.  This just means that when the exchange rate begins fluctuating, it usually keeps fluctuating for a while.

Reference

Panorama.  Нацванк: "В Казахстане инфляция достигла исторического минимума." [National Bank: "In Kazakhstan, inflation reached its historic minimum."]  Week of April 21, 2015.