Sunday, June 9, 2013

Gross Domestic Unhappiness





Is national income good for the soul?


In Central Asia, when political leaders want to brag, they usually spout statistics about gross domestic product – the value, when sold on the market, of goods and services produced by the nation in a year.   One can hardly blame them.  Double-digit rates of growth in GDP have been common in the region since the turn of the century.

There are other ways to judge our performance.  We may measure how well that our national economy is doing, per person, in terms of wealth or income.  “Wealth” is the accumulation of savings, which in turn is unspent income.  Suppose that you made $6,000 in your part-time job this year.  Of that amount, you put $2,000 in your savings account; bought $2,000 of KazKommerzbank stock shares; and spent $2,000 on food and clothes.  Then your savings are $4,000.  The stock doesn’t count as consumption, because you can’t enjoy it in the same way as a cone of ice cream; it’s just a parking lot for your money.  If you also saved $10,000 from past years, then your wealth is $14,000.  This figure indicates the lifestyle that you can support in the future.  The $6,000 of wages is your annual income, indicating how well that you can live this year without dipping into your wealth.  Income is a yearly inflow into your accounts; wealth is a stock, the value of your assets at a given time.
  
Before The wealth of nations appeared in 1776, scholars had thought that the nation’s wealth depended on its gold or silver.  Spain was rich because it had hauled tons of the precious metals from the New World.

We owe our modern notion of national wealth to Adam Smith, who attributed it to labor productivity – the amount that a typical worker can produce.  If she can figure out how to produce shirts more cheaply, then we can buy more shirts with given savings.  Wealth  increases in terms of what it can buy. 

Popes and Marxists

Productivity shapes income as well as wealth.  A Nobel-laureate economist, Robert Solow, pointed out that you could produce more cheaply if you had more capital to work with.  (“Capital” is anything man-made used in production: Machine tools, office towers, knowledge of accounting.)  Nations with more capital per worker can sustain higher levels of income per person.  Ethiopia is poor partly because its workers have few machines. 

Human capital – such as education and training – are particularly important to growth, noted the Nobel laureate Robert Lucas. Although this sounds obvious now, it was revolutionary.  The classical world didn’t appreciate knowledge about production and offered no means by which you could profit by it, wrote Ronald Wirtz.  In contrast, Americans have accumulated human capital rapidly in part because their universities compete for students.  The strength of private universities in the U.S. is virtually unique in the world, according to economists Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz.

These perspectives presume that wealth or income per capita is the most reliable measure of human well-being because they are material.  A 19th-century pope dissented.  In countering Marxists of the 1890s, who threatened to revolutionize Europe, Leo XIII defended property rights but added:

"...[I]n the case of the worker, there are many things which the power of the state should protect; and, first of all, the goods of his soul. For however good and desirable mortal life be, yet it is not the ultimate goal for which we are born, but a road only and a means for perfecting, through knowledge of truth and love of good, the life of the soul."

In the Sixties, Pope Paul VI reinforced the point: "Increased possession is not the ultimate goal of nations nor of individuals. All growth is ambivalent."  Income per capita is merely a means to a spiritual end.

Income per capita is a limited measure of human well-being because it fails to account for leisure, notes Robert Forrestal.  Over the past few decades, the entry of women into the labor market has increased.  In Kazakhstan, the number of women in the labor force rose 12.7% in seven years.  Even over the period of financial crisis, 2008 to 2010, the number rose 1.5%.  Such a surge into the labor market may raise income per capita, but at the loss of leisure (see the Notes).  “Economists simply cannot tell whether society is better off or worse off in this case.”  But women choose to work, so on average they surely must gain.

Bhutan’s way

The larger point – that income per capita does not fully measure well-being – is well-taken.  The United Nations measures human welfare with the Human Development Index, which reflects life expectancy, educational standards and individual purchasing power.  For example, Costa Rica has ranked much higher in its human development score than in its total output per capita. In the early 2000s, Costa Rica placed 76th by total output per capita but 42nd by human development. The discrepancy occurred because the average Costa Rican lived longer, learned more, and drank cleaner water than did residents of other nations with similar average incomes.  In 2004, the United States placed only eighth among all nations, in terms of the index.  Norway and Sweden led the list, reported the Financial Times..

One Nobel laureate economist uses death rates to analyze economic performance.  To Amartya Sen, the way that nations handle famine, health care, sexual and racial inequality, and poverty may reflect economic progress more truly than does income.

Skeptical of income estimates, some nations have adopted alternative measures of well-being.  The tiny nation of Bhutan judges its economy annually by a measure of Gross National Happiness.  One of its indicators is environmental quality, reported The Economist.  Conventional measures of gross domestic product do not subtract environmental damages; in fact, a rise in pollution will boost GDP, by increasing demand for health care.  To the contrary, Bhutan regards forests – which cover nearly three-fourths of its land -- as contributing to its Gross National Happiness.  But another indicator of its Happiness, the preservation of culture, may measure xenophobia.  Bhutan discourages Hindu immigrants from Nepal. 

To measure national income, economists sum up payments to input owners: Wages and salaries, profits, interest payments and rent.  Another approach is to sum all spending on production, since a tenge of spending is a tenge of income to someone.  Total spending is gross domestic product.  In developing countries, estimates of national income may fall short of GDP when people don’t report all of their income to the tax agency.  The difference measures the underground economy.  In Nigeria, Egypt, and Thailand, the underground economy has accounted for nearly three of every four dollars spent, noted economist John McMillan. –Leon Taylor, tayloralmaty@yahoo.com


Notes

Denote the number of adults in the labor force as LF, the number not in the labor force as NLF, total wage income as WI, and total nonwage income as NWI.  Then income per adult is a weighted sum of the sources of income, where the weights are the labor force share of all adults and 1 minus that share:

YPC = [LF/(LF + NLF)](WI/LF) +  [NLF/(LF + NLF)](NWI/NLF).

Denote the average labor wage as w, a decreasing function of LF, and the average nonlabor wage as nw, assumed constant.  Then, by definition,  

YPC = [wLF + nwNLF]/[LF + NLF]

Assume that NLF is a constant.  Then

dYPC/dLF = [1/(LF + NLF)][w + (dw/dLF)LF – (wLF + nwNLF)/(LF + NLF)].

For simplicity, set nw = 0.  With manipulations, dYPC/dLF is positive if

(w/LF)[NLF/(LF + NLF)] > dw/dLF.

An increase in the labor force raises income per adult if the magnitude of the wage response is less than the ratio of the wage to the labor force, weighted by 1 minus the labor force share of adults.  This is most likely when the wage is high and the labor force share of adults is small – conditions that may describe a resource-intensive developing economy.


Good reading

The Economist.  The pursuit of happiness.  December 18, 2004.

Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence Katz.  The shaping of higher education in the United States and New England.  Regional Review.  Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.  Q4 2001.  On line.

Forrestal, Robert.  Economic development for the 21st century: New measures of well-being.  The region.  Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.  June 1994.  The source of the papal quotes. 

Lucas, Robert.  Lectures on economic growth.  Harvard University Press.  2004.

McMillan, John.  Reinventing the bazaar.   Norton.  2002.

Sen, Amartya.  Development as freedom.  Anchor.  2000.

Solow, Robert.  Growth theory: An exposition.  Oxford University Press.  2000.

Williams, Frances.  Diversity “must be embraced” to ensure stability in globalizing world.  Financial Times. July 16, 2004.

Wirtz, Ronald A.  The new (and improved) economy.  The Region.  Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.  June 2000.  On line.



References

The statistical agency of Kazakhstan.  Labor indicators by gender 2003-2010.  Online. 

No comments:

Post a Comment