What
motivates authoritarian rulers in Central Asia?
Paul R. Gregory. The
political economy of Stalinism: Evidence from the Soviet secret archives. Cambridge
University Press. 2004.
308 pages.
More than two decades after the massive
heart attack of the Soviet Union, scholars
debate the reasons for the collapse. To
Austrian economists like Friedrich Hayek, a planned economy cannot induce the
information from individuals that generates trade. Had Steven Jobs not known the prices and
quantities bought of personal computers, he might not have been able to gauge
the potential profits in a pocket-sized device (assuming that he could have
kept them). Socialist economists blame
the men rather than the blueprint.
Planning might have worked had the politically powerful not been intent
on pocketing gains. To use Joseph
Berliner’s analogy, did the Soviet economy implode because of the jockey or the
horse? “What we know for certain,”
writes Paul Gregory, who has studied Soviet economies and their progeny for
four decades, “is that the administrative-command system survived longer than
Hayek and [Ludwig von] Mises would have expected and, at its peak in the 1960s
and 1970s, it constituted a credible military threat as a world superpower.”
The Austrians failed to anticipate this
qualified success because their model was too simple, Gregory argues. Bureaucrats had incentives to gather
information informally, but not necessarily to share it with ostensible
superiors. Brezhnev faced the same
problem that torments main shareholders today in the United States – the agent may not
do the bidding of the principal.
The
two-arm bandit
To explain Stalin, Gregory puts forth four
models of a dictator – models that may apply in Central Asia
today. The first and least likely is the
“scientific planner”, who merely defines benevolent rules for divvying up
resources among the population and leaves the decisions to the
technocrats. In contrast, the
“stationary bandit” manages the economy in order to ensure its long-run growth
and subsequently the nation’s political stability. (Gregory attributes this model to the late,
great American economist Mancur Olson.)
Both
types of dictators may engender economic growth; but clearly other types proliferate,
somewhat in the manner of stinkweeds. The “selfish dictator” cements his political
support by bribing or bullying the powerful.
Finally, the “referee-dictator” presides over the internecine struggles
of interest groups in order to make himself indispensable to them. (Yet another Olsonian concept.)
With respect to Stalin, we can dispose of
the scientific-planner model rather quickly.
Also, his iron grip on the Soviet economy and politics would rule out
the referee-dictator model. Choosing between
the two remaining models is complicated by the lack of reliable statistics, Gregory argues.
From specialized studies of output,
investment, rubles and other topics, Gregory concludes that the Kremlin horse
had thousands of jockeys, some of whom were superiors to others and all of whom were elbowing for position.. “Each superior faces an uncooperative and
untruthful subordinate who can only be moved to positive action by force. One dictator alone could bring little force
to bear. Each dictator requires
minidictators under him to coerce action at the next level.” This inelasticity in the economy reduced
output. “Virtually all economic
instructions were based on the principle that this year’s activity would be
last year’s plus a minor adjustment. The
massive imbalances were resolved by arbitrary interventions by the thousands of
‘dictators’ empowered to intervene.
There could be no general rules because they would have interfered with
the authority of officials to intervene….In effect, the economy was frozen in
place as the other world economies progressed.”
Regardless of its motivation, the dictator’s urge to command inhibited
economic growth. Perhaps this principle
is not entirely alien to Central Asia. -- Leon
Taylor, tayloralmaty@gmail.com
Good
reading
Hayek, F. A. The use of knowledge in society. American
Economic Review 35. 1945. Argues that only free markets can collect
essential economic information from individuals, through millions of their exchanges.
Olson, Mancur. The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard
University Press. 1971.
Small interest groups may dominate large ones because their benefits per
member are larger and their organizational costs smaller.
Olson, Mancur. The
rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social
rigidities. Yale University
Press. 1982.
No comments:
Post a Comment