Why did OPEC's decision rattle futures markets?
In the last six months, during which oil
prices on the futures market declined, they plunged most steeply immediately
after the November 27 decision of the Organization of Petroleum-Exporting
Countries (OPEC) not to reduce its supply, perhaps because of a prisoner’s
dilemma. Brent prices fell by $6 to $71.25 per barrel, reported Reuters. Why did speculators respond to OPEC by
dumping oil securities?
The most reasonable explanation would be
that they believed that the decision would create an excess supply of oil. Either supply would rise or demand would
fall. Let’s consider each possibility.
Could OPEC’s decision have increased
supply? It’s hard to see how. Non-OPEC producers (like Russia and Kazakhstan ) would not respond by
increasing their own supply since, given demand, this would create an
excess. They might have stepped up
production had OPEC voted to cut back, for this might have freed up some demand
for themselves. Indeed, this very possibility
might have led OPEC to maintain its existing supply.
Surely, then, OPEC’s decision would lead to
a fall in demand. But this doesn’t make
sense, either. Why would buyers cut back
in response to a confirmation of the usual supply?
Seeing
is disbelieving
In short, it is not reasonable to think
that OPEC’s policy could increase excess supply and thus cut oil prices. So why did investors immediately respond by
selling oil short?
Perhaps they considered not the actual
effect of the decision but the perceived
effect. If the typical investor
believes, correctly or otherwise, that the policy would increase supply, then
it makes sense to get out of oil. With
apologies to Robert Shiller, one might call this an “irrational lack of
exuberance.”
The weakness of this approach is that an
investor who focuses on actual demand and supply will eventually profit at the
expense of short sellers, if market conditions dominate prices over the course
of a year or more.
For example, some analyses suggest that
global oil prices are falling because of an (undocumented) excess supply of one
million barrels per day in West Texas Intermediate oil. Even if the excess supply does exist, it
would be trivial in the context of a global market of more than 90 million
barrels per day, according to data from the United States Energy Information
Administration. It is not reasonable to
think that, given demand, a rise in supply of about 1% would lead to a fall in
price of 30% or 40%. But if investors
think that such fallacies are commonly accepted, then they may sell oil short
for profit, at least until a sense of reality prevails. –Leon
Taylor tayloralmaty@gmail.com
Notes
1.
In the game called “prisoner’s dilemma,” each player chooses a strategy
that most benefits him given whatever the other player would do – yet the
overall outcome is worse for both players than a cooperative solution would
be. In OPEC’s decision, each country
might prefer to maintain its own output regardless of whether other countries
would maintain or reduce theirs. But the
general outcome might be worse for OPEC than a commitment by all its members to
reduce output.
References
Alex Lawler, David Sheppard and Rania El Gamal. Saudis block OPEC output cut, sending oil
price plunging. Reuters. November 27, 2014.
Robert Tuttle. Brent, WTI slump to 4-year low as OPEC keeps
quota steady. Bloomberg. November 28, 2014.
No comments:
Post a Comment