Why did Kazakhstan balk at leasing farmland to foreigners for long terms?
by Dmitriy Belyanin
In
many transition economies, the government restricts farmland sales or bans them
outright. This article looks at a recent
attempt to extend tenant rights in Kazakhstan.
The land reform and opposition to it
In late April, protests in Aktobe, Semey and Atyrau
demonstrated the unpopularity of farm sales to foreigners. In fact, such sales are illegal. But the
President of Kazakhstan, Nursultan Nazarbayev, explained that land would not be
sold to foreigners -- the new policy would simply increase the lease from 10 to
25 years. The longer lease would enable
foreigners to make a reasonable return, argued Gulzhan Karagusova, deputy of the Majilis, the lower house of Parliament.
Indeed, foreigners leased only 6% of all farmland, out of which 2% was leased
by Kyrgyzstanis, 2% by Uzbekistanis, and the rest mainly by Germans and Dutch,
reported Lada.kz.
Kasymzhomart Tokayev, the chairman of Kazakhstan’s
Senate, said the government should explain the new land code well and close
loopholes that would let foreigners buy farmland, said Ruslan Bakhtigareyev of
the Regnum information agency. But this did not satisfy protesters.
In the first week of May, Nazarbayev threw in the towel. He
imposed a moratorium on the new land code until 2017, and he demanded a
commission that would redesign land reforms, according to Tengri News.
Yerbolat Dosayev, Minister of the National Economy, resigned after the
moratorium, and Asylzhan Mamytbekov, Minister of Agriculture, received a strict
reprimand from the President. He too
quit at the end of the week, reported Alexander Konstantinov, of Kommersant.
On June 15, the Majilis decided that until the end of
2016, foreigners could no longer lease land.
Neither can the government privatize land to Kazakhstanis, said Tamara
Vaal of the Vlast’ Internet magazine.
Options for controlling contamination
The furor over long-term farm rents to foreigners highlights
Kazakhstani fears of poisoned land and unhealthy food. There are no grounds for some of these fears:
Increasing the lease strengthens incentives to avoid long-run
contamination. But consolidating small
farms can create problems. While small
farmers are not likely to use lots of pesticides and chemical fertilizers, large
farms might, since they act on scale economies.
In particular, Chinese manufacturers and farmers have a reputation for
pollution. Chinese farmers use 1.3
million tons of pesticides annually, which is 2.5 times the world average. In 2014, total contaminated soil in China was
estimated by the Ministry of Environmental Protection and the Ministry of Land
and Natural Resources at 24.5 million hectares, about a fifth of all
farmland. Later, the Minister of
Agriculture said 40% of farmland was contaminated and eroded, reported Lyan Hua
of Epochtimes.ru.
Though Beijing plans to reduce pollution and soil
contamination, this may be done by relocating enterprises abroad. To diversify the economy and to replace
revenue lost through plummeting oil prices, the government of Kazakhstan might cheerfully
accept the chance to increase crops at the expense of quality. Kazakhstan has sparsely populated land, and
labor costs that declined in dollar terms due to tenge depreciation; so it can attract
Chinese farmers, though government statistics suggest that this has not yet
been the case. Though the government can inspect soil for contamination, it
will have trouble enforcing regulations. After all, it’s hard to track poisons
to their source. Even if the government
can, it may balk at the consequences of reducing farm supply – i.e., higher
food prices.
Two more promising approaches are to restrict the
supply of pesticides and fertilizers or – even better -- to tax them for
pollution damages. Both approaches increase food prices, but pollution taxes
force the producer to take into account the harm due to another pound of
pesticides. An example may help. Suppose that the pound would inflict 50,000
tenge of damages, but the producer would profit by only 30,000 tenge by selling
the pound. Since the tax would exceed
the profit, the producer will not sell that pound. And that’s the right decision, because the pound’s
value to society (reflected by the profit) is less than its cost (reflected by
the tax). On the other hand, if the
potential profit is 60,000 tenge, the producer will sell the pound and pay the
tax for a net gain of 10,000 tenge. That again is the right decision, because
the benefits of the pesticide justify the little bit of pollution. Indeed, in
the West, pesticides seem to be valuable, since most farmers are willing to pay
high prices for them. A 10% price hike
cuts demand by only about 2% to 5%, estimated Pina and Forcada.
Kazakhstan is not likely to adopt the pollution tax
soon, largely because environmentalists think it gives producers too much
leeway (although the green movement in the US is gradually warming to the
idea). However, green taxes can raise
government revenues. For example, Mexico
began taxing in 2014. It divided pesticides into five categories,
depending on toxicity, and it levied pollution tax rates of 3-4.5%, half of the
permanent rates, reported the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD).
Impact on
landowners and tenants
In the short run, landowners may benefit more from the
lease reform than renters would. In most
markets, demand and supply affect price and quantity. For example, an increase in the supply of
kefir drinks will lower the price, since otherwise stores can’t sell the
additional drinks. But land is an
unusual commodity: It’s fixed in supply.
Changes in its price depend entirely on demand, so the price can be
volatile; if demand rises, supply cannot rise and thus reduce the increase in
price. The land reform would raise
demand by enabling foreigners to lease it for longer than before. Land prices would climb, and landowners would
profit. Land rents must also rise, since
otherwise landowners would sell their land rather than lease it out. Tenants would lose.
In the long run, Kazakhstanis could gain from the
reform, since it would attract from abroad more productive uses of the land. In
principle, the new uses must be more productive and profitable than the old
uses, since otherwise foreigners would take no interest in the land.
Wait, I’ll explain. In the long run, the price of land
must equal its expected value. After
all, were the price lower than the value, buyers would bid it up because they
expect to profit. And were the price
higher than the value, owners would sell the land, and their competition for
buyers would lower the price. To clear the land market, the price must equal
the value, leaving zero profits to the additional buyer. But a foreign buyer could introduce a new use
of the land that raises its value above its price, yielding her profit. As
Kazakhstanis adapt this new use to their own plots, their economy may grow more
rapidly than before.
But competition produces losers as well as winners. As
a new member of the World Trade Organization, Kazakhstan must cut farm
subsidies. Small Kazakhstani farmers
will risk bankruptcy -- especially if Chinese farmers, who have the technology
to create cheap foods, can buy or rent land.
The bankrupt and the unemployed will migrate to cities, leaving behind
sparsely populated and impoverished areas.
Some residents may join extremist groups.
On the other hand, sales of farmland to foreigners
could ensure that it remains useful, since abandoned land would eventually be
sold for productive use. Residents may
find work, though not necessarily at wages higher than those that prevailed in
the era of subsidies. On one hand, yes,
the new farms will raise the demand for workers and thus their pay. But on the other hand, large new employers
will dominate rural labor markets, and they will take advantage of their market
power by cutting wages to the point where the additional worker is indifferent
between accepting the job or turning it down.
Economists have a special term for a labor market
dominated by a single employer – a monopsony. This market is inefficient because the
employer can’t raise the wage enough to keep a productive additional
worker. Why not? Because, in order to avoid labor disputes, he
would have to raise the wage for everyone else as well. That would cost him
major money.
Foreign exchange market considerations and
forecasting
Since the tenge has been weakening relative to the
dollar and the yuan, the Chinese might lose money by farming here: Most of
their revenues would be in tenge, and their costs in dollars and renminbi. It’s unlikely that Chinese farmers would buy
domestic inputs, since Kazakhstan does not produce enough farm equipment and
seeds. The Eurasian Union, which bought
a tenth of Kazakhstan’s exports in 2015, according to Kaznext Invest, enables
farmers here to sell more, but the recession in Russia impedes its imports. Processors and retailers of Kazakhstani-made
farm goods may still demand staple products, such as wheat from northern
Kazakhstan; but the situation is more complicated for more sophisticated
products, demand for which is more responsive to the price.
Moreover, Kazakhstan faces competition in the CIS.
Uzbekistan’s president, Islam Karimov, vows to substitute Uzbek exports for
Turkish fruits and vegetables that no longer go to Russia, thanks to the
Kremlin’s embargo on Turkey, reported RBC.ru.
This also puts farmers in Kazakhstan at a
disadvantage. Russia would prefer to buy from Uzbekistan, in hopes that
expanded trade would induce Tashkent to support Russia politically. The European Union, which accounted for 56%
of Kazakhstan’s exports in 2015, has lost income due to the Russian embargo and
so will buy fewer farm exports from Central Asia. Moreover, the withdrawal of the United Kingdom
from the EU may weaken the euro, raising the euro price of imports from
Kazakhstan.
The situation will change after Russia’s economy
resumes growth or after the Russian embargo on European agricultural products
ends. But neither is likely to occur soon: Russian economy is still stagnating,
and the geopolitical struggle is aggravating.
The Kremlin’s Turkish policy illustrates its devotion to import
substitution in agriculture and its reluctance to cancel the embargo: Even
though Erdogan apologized for shooting down the war plane SU-24 in November
2015, Russia is still wary, allowing Turkish tourist flights but not imports of
Turkish food. According to Dmitriy
Medvedev, Prime Minister of Russia, restoring normal relations with Turkey does
not imply opening borders and allowing Turkish imports immediately. Producers
from other countries have taken advantage of the embargo to gain market share,
and Russia will keep buying products from them, asserts Mariya Bondarenko of RBC
Channel. Russian policy toward EU
imports is likely to be similar.
Of course, Russian buyers still lose from the higher
prices and the loss of diversity that stem from limits on imports. Domestic and non-EU firms cannot produce food
as efficiently as European exporters. However,
Russian propaganda argues that domestic products and imports from small
neighbors are healthier than European products, since they rely less on
genetically modified organisms. In
September 2015, the Russian government banned GM foods, said Reuters. This will raise food prices, but many believe
that it will improve foods. Rural
Russians support the embargo, despite their losses from European imports smuggled
into Russia through Belarus and Kazakhstan.
This does not imply that the embargo will be
permanent. But the Kremlin may keep it
going for a while in hopes that Eurosceptic political parties in Europe will undermine
the sanctions someday.
In any event, land rents in Kazakhstan can’t fully
offset the loss in government revenues from decreasing oil prices. One
preliminary study estimates that a 25-year lease would raise net revenues that
the government would receive on farmland, relative to 10-year leases, by
140%. But oil money accounts for half of
Astana’s revenues, according to Standard & Poor’s.
Experience of Russia
In Russia, plans are more explicit to rent land to the
Chinese. The government of the
Zabaikalski krai, a Siberian region east of the Baikal Lake, plans to lease 115
hectares of land to a Russian company with Chinese shareholders for 49 years
and then to attract Chinese laborers to cultivate the land. A preliminary protocol was signed in June
2015. Two hundred more hectares could be
leased. A preliminary rent of 250 rubles
per hectare annually was set.
The Chinese would hold no more than half of the jobs,
since Russians fear losing their own. But in reality, the Chinese find work in
Russia less attractive than employment in their own southern and eastern
provinces, where salaries are higher, report Andrey
Vinokurov and Elizaveta Mayetnaya of Gazeta.ru.
According to Konstantin Ilkovskiy, governor of the
region, the local government would own a fourth to a half of the enterprise and
Chinese investors would hold the rest.
There are no special preferences for China, and any Russian investor may
be considered. The agreement was to be
signed in the 1st quarter of 2016, and farming would begin in May, said
Interfax.
Like Kazakhstanis, Russians protested land
leases. In August 2015, in Chita, the
capital of the Zabaikalski Krai, 150 thousand people, mainly supporters of the
Communist Party of Russia, demanded that the government resign, reported Iliya
Barinov of the TASS information agency.
The government of the Zabaikalski Krai selected the
Chinese company Zoje Resources Investment as the lease-holder. But in February
2016, the firm reneged on its promise to rent, according to Flash Siberia. This
leaves the government with 800 thousand unused hectares, said the Vedomosti
newspaper. For Russia as a whole, 56
million hectares of agricultural land are unused, according to Ruslan Ostashko
of the Political Russia magazine. In his view, the lease of land to
foreign investors is common, and people should not fear Chinese investors more
than, say, Saudi or Indian investors.
Other countries offer similar cases. The Chinese cultivate 3 million hectares of
farmland in Ukraine, several hundred hectares in Tanzania, 10 thousand hectares
in Cameroon (mainly for rice), 100 thousand hectares in Zimbabwe, 2.8 million
hectares in Congo and 2 million hectares in Zambia.
Predictions
Fears of protests make unlikely the completion of a
deal with Chinese investors in Russia and the extension of foreign leases in
Kazakhstan. However, since Russia has so much land, and since BRICS must
strengthen their ties, it might be easier to convince the Russians to make the
deal than to persuade Kazakhstanis. But since the Kremlin appeals to health concerns
of consumers, it would still have to demonstrate that food quality would not decay. Having a less diversified economy, Kazakhstan
will find it more difficult than Russia does to avoid unpopular measures to
raise revenues by boosting food production. The lease may be lengthened next
year anyway, depending on politics and oil prices. Both countries may also try to attract
tenants from economies with good environmental reputations.
Conclusions
Lease and sale of farm hectares can boost land use and
production, but many people in transition economies oppose extending these
practices to foreigners. Though the
Chinese rent lots of land in other countries, their reputation for
environmentally unfriendly practices daunt Kazakhstanis and Russians. Many fear losing their jobs to Chinese
immigrants. These concerns, however groundless, led to protests that induced the
governments to rethink their initiatives.
Environmental effects can be mitigated with toxicity standards or pollution
taxes. The latter policy is economically
efficient, though the governments of Kazakhstan and Russia are unlikely to rely
on it.
Dmitriy Belyanin has a Master’s degree of
Business Administration in Finance and a Bachelor of Arts degree in Economics
from KIMEP University. Since 2007, he
has been writing on issues in economics and finance ranging from stock markets
to environmental economics. He is the associate editor of this blog.
References
Bakhtigareyev, R.
Protest meetings in Kazakhstan -- too much time was wasted. Regnum. http://regnum.ru/news/polit/2127353.html.
2016.
Bondarenko, M.
Medvedev said that no decision was made concerning cancelling the ban on
Turkish vegetables. RBC. http://www.rbc.ru/politics/05/07/2016/577ba1cd9a79472ea337531b?from=newsfeed. 2016.
Barinov, I. A
protest meeting against renting out land to a Chinese company took place in
Chita. TASS. http://tass.ru/obschestvo/2220046. 2015.
BBC. Why did
hundreds of people in Kazakhstan go to a protest meeting against privatization
of lands by foreigners for a 25-year term? - BBC. CA-News.org.
http://ca-news.org/news:1186237. 2016.
Hua, L. In
China, 40% of farmland degraded.
Epochtimes.ru. http://www.epochtimes.ru/v-kitae-degradirovalo-40-pahotnyh-zemel-98952281/. 2014.
Interfax. Land
in the Zabaikalye will be rented by a Russian enterprise with Chinese
capital. http://www.interfax.ru/russia/449823. 2015.
Interfax Kazakhstan.
The President of Kazakhstan declared a moratorium on several amendments
to the land code, which created an echo in society. Express-K.
http://www.express-k.kz/news/?ELEMENT_ID=73109. 2016.
Kaznex Invest.
An analysis of the state of external trade in Kazakhstan. 1st
quarter of 2015. http://www.kaznexinvest.kz/napr/analytics/export/trade/Analiz_vneshney_torgovli_1_kvartal_2015.pdf. 2015.
Konstantinov, A.
The land reform frightened Kazakhstan.
http://www.kommersant.ru/doc/2982494. 2016.
Lada.kz. Deputy
Karagusova blamed journalists for the political din surrounding the land code. https://www.lada.kz/another_news/38327-otvetstvennost-za-shumihu-vokrug-zemelnogo-kodeksa-deputat-karagusova-vozlozhila-na-zhurnalistov.html.
2016.
Nur.kz.
Foreigners do not wait in lines for land in Kazakhstan. https://www.nur.kz/1120456-karagusova-inostrancy-ne-vystraivayu.html. 2016.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD). Mexican fiscal reform
environmental taxes: Carbon tax, tax on pesticides. https://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-global/Session%203%20-%20LUNA.pdf. 2014.
Ostashko, R.
How Siberia was being leased out to the Chinese. Political Russia. http://politrussia.com/society/kak-sibir-kitaytsam-276/. 2015.
Pina, C.
Forcada, S. Effects of an
environmental tax on pesticides in Mexico.
http://www.inecc.gob.mx/descargas/dgipea/effects_env_tax_pesticides.pdf. 2004.
RBC.ru.
Uzbekistan promised Russia substitutes for Turkish vegetables and
fruits. http://www.rbc.ru/economics/26/04/2016/571f798d9a79479cf5ce3388. 2016.
Reuters. Government
decides to ban GMO food production in Russia: Deputy PM. CNBC. http://www.cnbc.com/2015/09/23/govt-decides-to-ban-gmo-food-production-in-russia-deputy-pm.html. 2015.
Standard & Poor’s.
S&P affirms long-term sovereign credit ratings of Republic of
Kazakhstan at ‘BBB,’ outlook negative.
September 11, 2015. Online.
Tengri News.
Nazarbayev imposed a moratorium on amendments to the land code. https://tengrinews.kz/kazakhstan_news/nazarbaev-nalojil-moratoriy-na-popravki-v-zemelnyiy-kodeks-293904/. 2016.
Vaal, T. The
President signed a law suspending several norms of the land code. https://vlast.kz/novosti/18148-prezident-podpisal-zakon-o-priostanovlenii-dejstvia-nekotoryh-norm-zemelnogo-kodeksa.html. 2016.
Vinokurov, A.
Mayetnaya, E. “Great Chinese
plans” in the Zabaikaliye. Gazeta.ru. http://www.gazeta.ru/politics/2015/06/23_a_6852465.shtml. 2016.
No comments:
Post a Comment