Saturday, December 23, 2017
Friday, December 15, 2017
Pandora’s revenge
In August 2015, the central bank of Kazakhstan took
its mitts off the exchange rate, leaving it to the vagaries of the currency
market. From July to September, the number of tenge trading for a dollar rose from
187 to 258 – and averaged 366 in January, a virtual doubling in five months. In
other words, the amount of foreign goods that tenge holders could buy nearly
halved. Who suffered most in this drastic depreciation?
At first glance, you would think that the rich had
more to lose than the poor. Those with tenge wealth saw their dollar value
vanish. The poor had no wealth, much less tenge wealth, so they got off
scot-free.
At second glance, things are not so simple. A depreciation raises local prices, since it
raises foreign demand for local goods, forcing residents to compete for them by
paying more. Some prices rise faster
than others. Who is unlucky enough to face these prices?
A recent study addressed this question by analyzing
the 1994 crash of the Mexican peso.
Political violence and other factors that year caused investors to lose
faith in the peso. To keep it from
weakening in terms of the dollar, the central bank bought pesos and sold
dollars. Since the peso was overvalued,
investors dumped it. By December, the central bank was running out of dollars,
so it floated the peso. The currency tanked, prices soared, and a few banks
collapsed. Sound familiar?
In their careful study of the Mexican crisis, Javier Cravino
and Andrei Levchenko concluded that prices paid by the poorest tenth of the
population nearly doubled while those paid by the richest tenth rose three
fourths. This happened partly because the rich spent more of their income on
services than the poor did. Most services are bought at home, not abroad; so
when the currency goes south, their prices rise less rapidly than those of
traded goods like grain. Even within a
category like food, prices rose more rapidly for the poor, who were accustomed
to buying cheap food from abroad.
Overall, in the two years following the swooning of the peso, the
purchasing power of the poor fell by half but declined less rapidly – by 40% --
for the rich.
Did the 2015 tenge crisis worsen the income
distribution in Kazakhstan as well? A
question, perhaps, for the National Bank. --Leon
Taylor, tayloralmaty@gmail.com
Good
reading
Aldo Musacchio. Mexico's financial crisis of
1994-1995. Harvard Business School
Working Paper. No. 12–101. May 2012.
Wikipedia.
Mexican peso crisis. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Mexican_peso_crisis
References
Javier Cravino and Andrei A. Levchenko. 2017. The distributional consequences of large
devaluations. American Economic Review 107(11): 3477–3509. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20151551.
National Bank of Kazakhstan. Official exchange rates on average for the
period. www.nationalbank.kz
Monday, December 4, 2017
Higher miseducation
Has Kazakhstan's educational policy gone astray?
In higher education, Kazakhstan doesn’t harvest the
forest because it perceives only a few trees.
During the early years of independence, the government
cut back sharply on its funding of colleges, which now amounts to less than a
third of a percent of the size of the economy (measured as gross domestic
product), according to the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, a research group comprising rich nations. Of this amount, more than a
third goes to Nazarbayev University, which the government regards as the
country’s flagship among research universities, and to the Bolashak program,
which finances advanced study abroad.
This leaves less than a fifth of one percent of GDP of public funds for
all other schools of higher education.
Among them, the government favors vocational and
technical colleges. This year it announced its intent to make this education
free, which may accelerate the long-term rise in their share of all students of
higher education, already above half despite a slight drop in the past few
years. Free vocational education may be a step towards diversifying the economy
away from oil exports, which account for roughly a fourth of GDP.
The logic behind this policy is a little shaky. At the margin, graduates of vocational
schools will realize most of the value of their education in the form of higher
wages. As long as they can borrow money
for school, they seem likely to choose the right amount of education by
comparing its value to its cost (such as the wages foregone by studying rather
than working for three years).
Wild
swings
Yes, vocational education might also confer a value on
society, rather than on the graduate, by diversifying the economy, since this
mitigates the oscillations in GDP that stem from volatile oil prices. The youth
might not take this value into account when she mulls going to college. But aside from this, the market will provide
enough vocational education even if the students pay full tuition.
The area that may be under-funded is liberal arts
education, ranging from art history to political science. This education creates general skills for
solving such problems as how to reduce inequality in the nation’s distribution
of income – problems that matter to society but that do not necessarily offer
high wages motivating anyone to seek a solution. The
OECD notes that general problem-solving skills are much
weaker in Kazakhstan than in the West.
Liberal arts also promote a sense of civility among
graduates that makes life pleasant for all of us. The youth contemplating
college cannot cash in these benefits as higher wages, so he is likely to
ignore them when choosing his field of study.
A subsidy to the liberal arts may correct this deficiency.
The OECD has complained that Nazarbayev University’s
share of public funds is too large to benefit higher education. “At best, this
is an experiment that carries substantial risks: It is an open question whether
any excellence that the university may achieve can outweigh reduced funding for
the rest of the [higher education] system.” It could have said the same thing
about Kazakhstan’s skimpy funding of colleges in general. –Leon Taylor tayloralmaty@gmail.com
References
OECD (2017). Higher education in Kazakhstan 2017, Reviews
of national policies for education. OECD Publishing, Paris. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264268531-en
Tuesday, November 14, 2017
Sunday, October 8, 2017
Make America wait again
Stymied in building the Great Wall of Mexico, the
president of the United States is trying to brick up a bigger wall around
trade. Donald Trump berates the Germans
for their trade surplus with the US; proposes to rewrite a trade pact to limit
the surpluses of Mexico and Canada; and, I presume, would extend the same
principle to Kazakhstan’s surplus with the US, totaling $216 million in goods so
far this year. Trade deficits, Trump avers, weaken the US economy.
In reality, a trade deficit is a blessing in disguise. Recall that this deficit is the excess of goods
that a nation buys abroad (imports) over what it sells abroad (exports). If
Kazakhstan sells $3 million of oil to the US in exchange for $2 million of
automobiles, then the US has a trade deficit with Kazakhstan of $1 million. In
a sense, this cool million is a gift to the US. It doesn’t have to give up any
SUVs for the extra petroleum – just green pieces of paper called dollars, which
it can print virtually for free.
Of course, what tees off the Trumpists is the loss of
oil jobs in the US: Why shouldn’t America produce oil for itself? The answer is
that it’s better at producing cars -- that’s why Kazakhstan buys from Detroit.
Shifting derrick workers to auto factories (albeit indirectly) puts them in
more productive jobs where they can earn more. But this doesn’t happen
overnight, and the workers meanwhile are angry and unemployed. Hence President Trump.
The Trumpists fail to see that limits on trade
deficits harm the rest of the American economy.
To build another factory, Ford must borrow if it doesn’t have a few
spare billion bucks at hand. But it can’t borrow from foreigners unless they
have dollars, which they earn by selling oil and toys to the US. If Trumpists
block these sales, foreigners won’t have dollars to lend. So much for the
Trumpists’ vaunted plan for economic growth.
If Trumpists really want US firms to build plants,
then they can cut the federal deficit – that is, the amount that Washington
spends that it can’t cover with tax revenues. Reducing the deficit will free up
money to pay for factories. But in reality, the Trumpists propose tax cuts that
will swell the federal deficit. To pay for the new debts, the federal
government must borrow money in competition with firms. This will raise the
interest rate and thus the cost of building schools and warehouses. Trump’s real
motto: Make America Wait Again – wait for growth.
--Leon Taylor
tayloralmaty@gmail.com
Notes
A simple equation makes clear the ties of trade to the
rest of the national economy, by showing how the nation can raise money for
real investment (i.e., investment to build things, as opposed to financial
investment).
People either spend their income on products or taxes,
or they save it. Denote income as Y, consumption as C, taxes as T, and savings
as S. Then Y = C + S + T.
We can also think of income as the value of what the
nation creates. Its goods and services are either for consumers, firms,
government or foreigners. Denote products for consumers as C, for firms as I
(for real investment), for government as G, or for foreigners as X – M (exports
minus imports). So Y = C + I + G + (X - M).
Equate the two expressions for Y:
C + S + T = C + I + G + (X - M).
Simplify and solve for real investment:
I = S + (T - G) + (M - X).
This says three sources can finance investment:
Private savings, the government surplus (that is, tax revenues that the
government has not yet spent), and foreign savers (who earn dollars by selling
more to the US than they buy from it). The term M – X is the trade deficit,
which in this appendix includes services as well as goods.
The distinction between goods and services can matter.
In the second quarter of 2017, Kazakhstan had a surplus with the world in goods
of $4.2 billion – but a deficit in services of $1.1 billion.
References
Steve Munson, Joshua Partlow and Alan Freeman. US
neighbors see increasing risk of failure in NAFTA talks. Washington Post. October 7, 2017.
National Bank of Kazakhstan. Balance of payments of
the Republic of Kazakhstan: Analytic presentation. http://nationalbank.kz/?docid=199&switch=english
United States Census Bureau. Trade in goods with Kazakhstan. https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c4634.html
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)