While the rest of us are ringing in the new, some
folks would like to ring out old-fashioned environmental economics.
First, some background. Power plants burn fossil fuels, emitting carbon dioxide into the air
that raises global temperatures and vexes the climate. How can we cut carbon emissions that cause
global warming?
Economists recommend two policies. One is to issue a fixed
supply of permits to pollute, which firms could buy and sell among themselves.
Firms that could avoid polluting cheaply would sell their permits at profit to
firms that couldn’t. This would ensure
that we cut pollution by the desired amount as cheaply as possible. For
example, power plants with the latest technology for injecting carbon into the
ground would sell their pollution permits and opt for injection. The permits
would be bought by utilities without this technology – plants that could cut
emissions only at great cost; for example, by burning expensive natural gas
rather than cheap coal. The idea is that if, as a practical matter, we have to
have a little pollution, then we might as well get it from firms that would
have found it prohibitively costly to clean up. This will save jobs. (And this, by the way, is of moment to Kazakhstan, which
not only exports oil but burns coal for its own electricity.)
The second tool is a tax on each ton of carbon released
into the atmosphere. If the government believes that carbon is damaging, then
it will set the tax high. This will compel emitters to take into account the
environmental costs of their pollution. The end result is much the same as the
one for permits: Power plants that can inject carbon into the ground cheaply
will do so rather than pay a tax of, say, $50 per carbon ton. Once again, we
get cleanup at a bargain-basement price.
But a prominent American journalist, Justin Gillis, is
skeptical of the carbon tax. “...A carbon price is no magic bullet,” he writes.
“One of the biggest climate problems is poorly constructed buildings that waste
energy. A carbon price will not solve that problem, for the elementary reason
that the people who put up the buildings, and have an economic motive to skimp
on insulation and windows, are not the people who wind up paying the energy
bills.”
Actually, they are. Occupants of the energy-wasting
building must pay a hefty carbon tax, so they will pay little to rent this
building rather than an efficient one. The fall in rent will come out of
the pockets of the developer (who presumably owns the land) and the builders.
But carbon taxes do
pose a problem. Evidence is
rapidly piling up that we have underestimated the costs of global warming.
Since the tax rate is based on past estimates of the environmental cost,
polluters may face too low of a tax and thus emit too much. So we should ditch
carbon-price schemes, no?
The
power parable
For example, suppose that the utility providing
electricity to the inefficient building WasteCity pays a monthly carbon tax of
$100 because it burns coal. The utility
will pass on this tax to the occupant of WasteCity. She will move to the solar-powered building
WasteNot unless the owner and builder of WasteCity cuts her monthly rent by
$100.
No. We can use the permit rather than the tax. If we
think that environmental costs will keep rising at an unexpected rate, then we
can limit the amount of pollution by printing only a few permits. Yes, we could
have raised the carbon tax instead; but given all the uncertainty about the
consequences of global warming, it is hard to anticipate the tax rate that
would give us the right amount of cleanup. If we set a $100 tax, we don’t know
how many carbon tons we will get; but we do
know if we print permits for only a thousand tons. As a safety measure,
nothing beats a cap on permits. –Leon
Taylor tayloralmaty@gmail.com
Good
reading
William Baumol and Wallace Oates. The theory of environmental policy. Second
edition. Cambridge University. 1988.
Justin Gillis. Forget the carbon tax for now. The
New York Times. December 27, 2018.
No comments:
Post a Comment