Can
austerity work?
European officials are backing away from
tax increases and spending cuts – “austerity” – but cannot make clear to the
public what they want to do, reports The
New York Times. “European Union
officials insist that their economic policy has never been as dogmatic or
narrowly focused on spending cuts as critics claim, and say they have long
since moved beyond just austerity,” writes Andrew Higgins. “But unable to speak plainly in any of the
union’s 23 official languages, they have had trouble explaining their efforts
in a manner that ordinary people can understand.”
Let’s try English.
Consider an economy with many jobless
workers and closed factories. The
solution may be to spend more, raising the demand for what workers and plants
produce. If households won’t step up
spending – perhaps fearing that they will need the money later – then the
government can do so. This may not cost
the economy, because the workers and plants weren’t producing anything, anyway. The government is not crowding out any
production.
Now suppose that all workers and factories
are producing. Then additional spending
won’t stimulate output, because the economy is already producing as much as it
can. Prices will rise, not output. One solution is to accommodate the rise in
demand by expanding the economy’s capacity, by building factories and educating
workers. This will require people to
tighten their belts and to put more money in the banks, which will lend the
savings to producers for construction and education. (Firms acquire plants; workers acquire
learning.) In other words, people should
save more and spend less.
If the government now spends more, then it
will crowd out some of this investment.
By borrowing more from banks, the government strips them of savings that
otherwise would have been loaned to the producers. Unless the government’s projects are more
valuable than the private ones, economic growth will slow down, because the
economy is adding capacity slowly.
A
hole in the ace
The first problem – a lack of demand –
affects the short run. The second
problem – a lack of supply – affects the long run. The government can address both problems,
each at the appropriate time.
Some policymakers argue that austerity can
help the economy immediately by giving the government credibility. Before people will invest, they want to be
sure that the government will keep its word.
If it spends freely, racking up debts, then people may fear that it will
tax them eventually, regardless of earlier promises, in order to settle its
accounts. But lowering the debt-to-GDP
ratio is not the only way that the government can demonstrate its credibility. (GDP is gross domestic product – the size of
the economy.) If it has a history of
borrowing only in recession, or when it has a worthwhile project like building
needed highways, then investors may conclude that the government can pay off
its loans out of the tax revenues generated by the new economic activity, not
by taxing them.
Much of Europe
remains in recession, which may call for a short-run solution. Kazakhstan faces a long-run
problem. Its economy has been growing 8%
per year, on average, since 2000, and the unemployment rate now is only about
5%. The economy needs more capacity, but
the government’s history of reneging on tax deals with foreign investors is not
likely to attract them. Oil deposits
will, but that’s the only ace that the government happens to be holding.--Leon Taylor, tayloralmaty@gmail.com
References
Andrew Higgins. Europe
facing more pressure to reconsider cuts as a cure. The New
York Times. April 26, 2013.