Checking in with Malthus
Now
exceeding 7 billion, the world population has been rising by nearly a billion
souls per decade. True, the growth rate
has nearly halved since 1960, to 1.2% per year.
But the poorest populations have been growing at almost double the world
rate. They account for almost a fourth
of the addition to world population although they comprise only an eighth of
the total population. Five African
countries are growing by 3% or more per year, including Zimbabwe (3.1%). The Palestinian West Bank and Gaza Strip also
grow by 3%. No wonder demographers
suspect that population growth creates poverty, although the most
rapidly-growing nation, the small Gulf state Oman (9.2%), is rich, according to
World Bank data.
In Soviet
days, Soviet scholars fearfully anticipated rampant growth throughout the Central Asian
satellites. That hasn’t transpired. Three countries grow at the world rate or
slightly lower: Kazakhstan , Kyrgyzstan and Turkmenistan . The largest populace in the area, Uzbekistan , is
growing faster (1.5%). But the
pacesetter for the region is its poorest nation, Tajikistan (2.2%), in line with
demographers’ expectations.
A simple
model, assuming a constant rate of growth, predicts more than 90% of the
fluctuation in population for most nations over a period of 10 or 15 years;
after that, the growth rate tends to change.
This suggests that a simple theory may explain the size of population –
and Thomas Malthus provided one, in 1798.
One of the first professional economists, Malthus argued that population
growth doomed humanity since the populace would expand more rapidly than food
supply. The amount of food per person
would fall until we starved. Famine,
pestilence and war would thin the population, raising the amount of food
available to each survivor until people had recovered enough to beget children
again. Then food supply per capita would
fall back to the subsistence level.
Charitable cruelty
We cannot
escape this cycle of catastrophe because – according to Parson Malthus -- we cannot
control our passions. Consequently, the
rate of population growth will be determined largely by the fertility rate (the
number of children born to an average woman), which changes slowly. (From 1965 to 2008, the fertility rate in
Kazakhstan fell just 27%, from 3.49 to 2.56 – but fell as low as 1.8, in 1998
and 2000.) So it’s no surprise to find
that most populations grew at a constant rate over the medium run. Food supply, on the other hand, depends on a
finite amount of land, so it grows linearly – that is, at a diminishing rate. The populace grows faster than the harvest.
Malthus’
dark vision extended to altruism. He opposed
welfare for the poor since it would merely encourage them to have more hungry
children. “Such charity was only cruelty
in disguise,” explained Robert Heilbroner, the late historian of economic
thought.
Calling Dr. Pangloss
Though
compelling, Malthus’ theory does not fit the facts. Since 1798, both the world population and
world income per capita have grown sharply.
Latter-day Malthusians, such as the Club of Rome , warn that catastrophe is just around
the corner; witness global warming.
Nevertheless, the past two centuries have given us a pretty good
dataset.
Anti-Malthusian
economists explain that an increase in
population density stimulates innovation, since more people can exchange more
ideas. Whatever the reason, some nations
would welcome a population boom. Russia lost
five million souls from 2000 through 2009, when its population dipped below 142
million, though it has grown slowly since then, to 143 million in 2012. An indicator of the future labor force, the
share of the population younger than 15, fell from 1990 through 2004 in China , Japan ,
Kazakhstan -- and sharply in
Russia ,
from about 22% to 15%. Maybe two heads are better than one, especially if one
head is young. --Leon Taylor tayloralmaty@gmail.com
Notes
1. The growth rates of national populations
reported here are annual averages for the period from 2000 through 2012, using
World Bank data. I estimated them with
this OLS model: Ln Pop(t) = a + r*Year, where ln
denotes a natural log and r is the
exponential rate of growth. R-squared
for most estimations exceeded .92 and usually exceeded .99.
2. Concerning the fertility rate in Kazakhstan: A measure of volatility, the ratio of the standard deviation to the mean, was .21 – lower than one might have expected, given the dramatic changes due to migration over the 1990s, and given that there were only 25 observations for the 44-year period.
2. Concerning the fertility rate in Kazakhstan: A measure of volatility, the ratio of the standard deviation to the mean, was .21 – lower than one might have expected, given the dramatic changes due to migration over the 1990s, and given that there were only 25 observations for the 44-year period.
Good reading
Karen
Hardee, Zhenming Xie, and Baochang Gu. Family
planning and women’s lives in rural China . International Family Planning
Perspectives 30(2): 68-86. 2004. A source of the material used here about China .
Karen
Hardee-Cleaveland and Judith Banister. Fertility
policy and implementation in China ,
1986-88. Population and Development Review 14(2): 245-286. June 1988.
Another source of the Chinese material.
Robert Heilbroner. The worldly philosophers. Touchstone. Seventh revised edition. 1999. Depicts Malthus vividly.
Thomas
Malthus. An essay on population. 1798. Online.
Brilliant and provocative.
Joseph
Schumpeter, Capitalism, socialism and
democracy. Harper. Third edition. 1950.
Argues that returns to producing ideas do not diminish as ideas
increase, because they don’t require finite resources – just imagination.
References
World
Bank. World Development Indicators. 2014.
Online. The source of estimates
used here for population levels, fertility rates, and the share of youths in
national populations.
No comments:
Post a Comment