Saturday, February 3, 2024

Are the very rich, very different? Well, yes



                                           Life in the fast lane. Photo credit: Getty Images


The rich, said F. Scott Fitzgerald, are very different from you and me. Yes, retorted Ernest Hemingway – they’re richer. 

How do Americans consume in comparison to Kazakhstanis? The typical American is 150% richer than the typical Kazakhstani (65,000 versus 26,000, in 2017 international dollars for 2022).

I estimated the amount spent by Americans out of an additional dollar of annual income over the period from 1990 through 2022. Consumption is final consumption expenditure (that is, the amount that consumers spend on goods and services in the final stage – the burger after MacDonald’s cooks it); Income is gross domestic product (the value of production in the US). I express both variables in 2015 international dollars, so they adjust for inflation and for changes in the exchange rate.  Time indexes the number of years that have passed since 1990. For 1990, Time = 1. For 1991, Time = 2, etc.  All data are from the World Bank.

 

Table 1: The marginal propensity to consume in the long run in the US

Regression results

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

R square

.997

 

 

 

 

 

 

Standard error

1.56E+11

 

 

 

 

 

 

Observations

32

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ANOVA

Df

SS

MS

F

Signif. F

 

 

Regression

1

2.19E+26

2.19E+26

9001.45

0.000

 

 

Residual

30

7.3E+23

2.43E+22

 

 

 

 

Total

31

2.2E+26

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Coefficients

T-stat

P-value

Lower 95%

Upper 95%

 

 

Intercept

2.89E+10

0.216

0.830

-2.4E+11

3.02E+11

 

 

GDP

0.823

94.88

0.000

0.805

0.841

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Table 1 shows that over the long run, Americans spend 82 cents of each additional dollar, a much higher rate than in Kazakhstan (65 cents).

The intercept is statistically insignificant. That is, consumption when Americans have zero income may well be zero even outside of the sample. This suggests that Americans should they have zero income would not consume by borrowing from future income. Of course, the case is not realistic, because the US has lots of income every year. But although the case is a logical extreme, it sheds light on the debate over whether Americans spend too much. These results suggest that over the past three decades, Americans have not consumed catastrophically.

The model explains virtually all variation in consumption over the years; R-square is over .99. It’s all about income.  There is not much room for additional explanatory variables.

 

Table 2: The marginal propensity to consume in the US in the short run

R Square

0.997

 

 

 

 

 

Standard Error

1.59E+11

 

 

 

 

 

Observations

32

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

ANOVA

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Df

SS

MS

F

Signif.F

 

Regression

2

2.19E+26

1.09E+26

4352.819

0.000

 

Residual

29

7.29E+23

2.52E+22

 

 

 

Total

31

2.2E+26

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Coefficients

T-stat

P-val

Lower 95%

Upper 95%

 

Intercept

1.11E+11

0.157

0.876

-1.3E+12

1.55E+12

 

GDP

0.814

10.968

0.000

0.663

0.966

 

Time

3.03E+09

0.119

0.906

-4.9E+10

5.53E+10

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Table 1 gives the Income coefficient that is the average over the 33-year period. This coefficient is thus for the long run. In contrast, Table 2 controls for the Time trend; that is, it controls for the long run. So its Income coefficient is the marginal propensity to consume in the short run.   

The short-run marginal propensity to consume (.814) is remarkably close to the long-run propensity (.823). This suggests that at the margin, Americans save the same way in the short run as in the long: The marginal propensity to save in both periods is about the same. Maybe Americans obtain financial information quickly and see no reason to update it later. Here, we interpret saving broadly: It includes the forced saving of tax payments as well as private saving. 

But in Kazakhstan, the marginal propensity to consume is much higher in the short run than in the long: .946 versus .645. Kazakhstanis may need time to gather financial information and adjust their savings (and thus consumption). This may speak to the inefficiency of financial markets in developing  economies.

The Time coefficient in Table 2 is statistically insignificant. US consumption has no time trend. Once again, it’s all about income. In contrast, Kazakhstani consumption falls over time, controlling for income, again perhaps because financial information improves over time, lifting savings and reducing consumption.   Leon Taylor, Baltimore tayloralmaty@gmail.com

Notes

For helpful comments, I thank but do not implicate Annabel Benson.

 

Reference

World Bank. World Development Indicators.  www.worldbank.org

 


No comments:

Post a Comment